Opções de pesquisa
Página inicial Sala de Imprensa Notas explicativas Estudos e publicações Estatísticas Política monetária O euro Pagamentos e mercados Carreiras
Sugestões
Ordenar por
Edmund Moshammer
Não disponível em português

Longer-term challenges for fiscal policy in the euro area

Prepared by Edmund Moshammer

Published as part of the ECB Economic Bulletin, Issue 4/2024.

1 Introduction

In the future, various longer-term challenges are likely to exert pressure on public finances in the euro area. On top of the existing fiscal burdens – as reflected in the high debt ratios in a number of euro area countries, which were exacerbated by the pandemic and the subsequent energy crisis – there are several important longer-term challenges for fiscal dynamics. This article starts by reviewing some of the most important challenges and discussing their fiscal relevance, with a focus on demographic ageing (Section 2), the end of the “peace dividend” (Section 3), digitalisation (Section 4) and climate change (Section 5). Acknowledging the uncertainties surrounding any quantification of these challenges, Section 6 then presents some tentative – purely indicative – estimates of the additional fiscal effort that could be required to ensure the long-term sustainability of public finances in the presence of such developments. The implications of digitalisation are excluded from that exercise, given the particular uncertainty that surrounds their quantification. Section 7 then provides some concluding remarks.

2 Fiscal costs of ageing societies

The euro area is experiencing demographic ageing. The region is witnessing a significant decline in fertility rates, coupled with steady increases in life expectancy, resulting in an ageing population. At the level of the European Union as a whole, average remaining life expectancy at the age of 65 has increased over the last two decades, rising from 17.8 years in 2002 to 19.5 years in 2022.[1]

This demographic ageing presents challenges for government finances. With the number of elderly citizens increasing relative to the working-age population, pay‑as-you-go pension systems face mounting financial pressures. Furthermore, ageing populations typically require more extensive healthcare services and long‑term care.

Developments in ageing-related public spending vary across euro area countries. The recently published 2024 Ageing Report provides long-term projections for the key drivers of ageing-related costs and their components (which comprise pensions, health care, long-term care and education) in EU Member States over the period 2022-2070.[2] In the baseline scenario, which assumes unchanged policies, the euro area on aggregate will face an increase in ageing-related expenditure of 1.4 percentage points of GDP relative to today, but this could increase to 4.0 percentage points in a risk scenario. And even in the baseline scenario five countries may need to increase their ageing-related spending by over 3 percentage points of GDP (Chart 1). The increase in the public cost of pensions has the highest variability across countries, given the varied nature of demographics and pension system arrangements at country level (e.g. the extent to which retirement ages are linked to life expectancy). The increased burden of ageing will require policy reforms or structurally increased savings in other areas.

Chart 1

Additional fiscal efforts required owing to ageing populations

(percentages of GDP)

Sources: 2024 Ageing Report and ECB calculations.
Notes: This chart shows, for each component, the average increase in ageing-related costs from 2023 to 2070, weighted by the cumulative product of the reciprocal interest-growth differential. This increase can be interpreted as the constant additional budget balance needed in all years to meet the fiscal burden of an ageing population. Public spending on pensions is net of tax revenues.

3 Fiscal costs of the end of the “peace dividend”

Russia’s war of aggression against Ukraine has prompted far-reaching discussions on security, military spending and geopolitical stability. NATO members in the euro area have responded to this challenge by announcing and implementing large increases in defence spending, which represents a significant reversal of previous trends. As the Cold War thawed, all major economies reduced their defence expenditure (Chart 2, panel a). The United States and the United Kingdom more than halved their spending, reducing it from over 10% of GDP in the 1950s to less than 5% as of the 1990s. Germany and France, in turn, reduced their spending from over 4% of GDP to less than 2% today. Using this “peace dividend”, governments refocused their budgets, targeting new priorities such as increased social welfare spending.[3] After Russia’s annexation of Crimea in 2014, all NATO members agreed to spend at least 2% of GDP on defence.[4] Since then – and especially following Russia’s full-scale invasion of Ukraine – the vast majority of euro area countries have increased their defence expenditure (Chart 2, panel b). If all euro area countries (including those that are not NATO members) were to increase their defence expenditure to 2% of GDP, this would result in an estimated €71 billion of additional spending annually – equivalent to 0.5% of euro area GDP.[5]

Chart 2

Public spending on defence

a) Long-term decline since the peak of the Cold War

(spending as a percentage of GDP, 1954-2022)

b) Changes since Russia’s annexation of Crimea in 2014

(spending as a percentage of GDP)

Sources: Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (SIPRI), NATO and Eurostat.
Notes: In panel a, data are sourced from SIPRI. In panel b, the asterisks denote non-NATO countries, where data are sourced from Eurostat and the blue bars refer to 2022. Data for other countries are sourced from NATO (press release from 7 July 2023).

Additional defence spending could potentially increase GDP growth in the EU, with positive implications for fiscal sustainability in the longer term, if it (i) is concentrated in R&D-intensive investment, (ii) does not crowd out other productive investment, and (iii) focuses on EU-based sources. According to the European Commission, using EU-based suppliers in defence contracts and, accordingly, shifting towards sourcing defence equipment and services from within the EU’s internal market could stimulate economic growth in the longer term. The Commission recently announced the European Defence Industrial Strategy, which encourages EU Member States to make strategic investments in their defence capabilities while promoting intra-EU collaboration and cooperation.[6] One of the key pillars of this strategy involves ensuring that defence products are readily available through the European Defence Technological and Industrial Base. This is about incentivising Member States to procure defence equipment and services from EU suppliers, thereby strengthening domestic defence industries, reducing reliance on external sources and enhancing resilience to any potential geopolitical shocks. According to the Commission, this has the potential to support the growth and development of EU-based defence companies, fostering innovation, job creation and technological advancement within the region. It would also produce multiplier effects across different sectors and ultimately increase fiscal revenues.

The economic impact of Russia’s war of aggression extends far beyond the realm of military spending. In the two years since the invasion of Ukraine, EU Member States and institutions have committed an estimated 0.55% of the EU’s annual GDP in bilateral short-term support.[7] Furthermore, the EU has also established a €50 billion Ukraine Facility covering the period 2024‑27. The World Bank estimates that Ukraine’s overall recovery and reconstruction needs will total around $486 billion over the next ten years.[8]

Moreover, in 2022 and 2023, governments were also forced to react to the resulting energy crisis and the high levels of inflation that followed. Indirectly, the war in Ukraine triggered a large temporary fiscal policy response at European level aimed at counteracting the high energy prices and the ensuing inflation, thus pointing to the multifaceted challenges posed by the ongoing conflict.[9] While governments should continue to roll back these energy-related support measures in 2024 to allow the disinflation process to proceed sustainably, the longer-term challenge of improving energy security in the EU will remain.

As the war in Ukraine is still ongoing and the geopolitical landscape is also characterised by instability in the Middle East and other parts of the world, the full long-term fiscal cost of the end of the peace dividend remains uncertain and is very difficult to estimate. For instance, the fragmentation of global trade could have severe implications for producers and consumers alike. If firms restructure their production chains in order to source inputs from countries that are geographically closer, rather than those with the most efficient production capabilities, their production costs will typically increase.[10] While the indirect fiscal effects are very difficult to quantify, they could be sizeable.[11] As a result, there continues to be significant uncertainty regarding the long-term fiscal consequences of these developments.

4 Fiscal costs of closing the digitalisation gap

The rising importance of digital value chains and transformative technologies is necessitating substantial investment in digital infrastructure and digital public services in order to maintain competitiveness. Before establishing the Recovery and Resilience Facility (RRF) in 2021, the European Commission estimated the EU’s digital investment gap vis-à-vis the United States and China at €125 billion per year (equivalent to around 0.9% of the EU’s GDP), calling for the resulting costs to be shared between the private and the public sector.[12] This will involve significant investment in digital infrastructure, particularly telecommunications networks.

In 2022, the EU adopted the Digital Decade Policy Programme 2030, a set of targets and objectives aimed at catching up in the area of digital transformation, supported by public investment. Around 70% of all funding for that programme – €117 billion in total – will come from the RRF, with €16.6 billion having been disbursed to fund the digital transition by March 2024 (Chart 3, panel a).[13] Under EU rules, at least 20% of all disbursed RRF funds must be spent on the digital transition. However, most Member States are exceeding this minimum threshold in their revised Recovery and Resilience Plans, with country‑specific allocations of RRF funds to the digital transition ranging from the minimum of 20% in Croatia and Slovenia to 48.1% in Germany. The degree of digitalisation still varies considerably across countries. In order to gauge progress towards the targets set, a Digital Economy and Society Index (DESI) has been devised (Chart 3, panel b). This is a composite index comprising 32 sub-indicators, 11 of which are directly linked to the Digital Decade. The short time horizon limits any causal inference, but estimates suggest that there is a significant correlation between DESI scores and GDP per capita, further reinforcing the ongoing Digital Decade agenda.[14] Digital investment that results in the strengthening of economic growth may, ultimately, also boost fiscal revenues.

Chart 3

Digital RRF expenditure and DESI scores

a) RRF disbursements targeting digital objectives: breakdown by policy area

(EUR billions; as at March 2024)

b) DESI 2023 scores

(as a percentage of target scores for 2030)

Sources: European Commission and ECB calculations.
Note: In panel b, the target for each of the four broad categories is a maximum score of 25 points.

5 Fiscal effects of climate change

Climate change poses major fiscal challenges for euro area economies. From the direct costs of extreme weather events to the broader economic implications of transitioning to a low-carbon future, the fiscal impact of climate change is multifaceted and requires comprehensive analysis and action. As outlined in the ECB’s climate and nature plan 2024-2025, central banks will need to improve their understanding of these drivers in order to deliver on their core objectives.

Extreme weather events – which may increase in frequency and severity as a result of climate change – pose immediate and tangible risks. The economic costs of floods, storms, heatwaves and droughts have increased sharply in recent decades, placing a substantial financial burden on governments.[15] Costs relating to disaster relief, infrastructure repair and healthcare services in the aftermath of such events place strain on public finances, diverting resources from other essential areas. At the same time, the burden of climate change is distributed unevenly across euro area countries. For example, the European Commission’s PESETA IV project estimates that welfare losses from climate change in southern Europe will be several times larger than in the north of Europe, mostly because of higher temperatures and water scarcity.[16] This uneven burden is further exacerbated by the fact that some countries which have historically suffered significant losses also have large insurance protection gaps.[17] Against that background, a recent European Commission discussion paper sheds light on the potential fiscal repercussions of extreme climate events.[18] The paper estimates that in a scenario where temperatures rise by 2°C globally in the long term, eight euro area countries could see their public debt-to-GDP ratio rise by over 2 percentage points by 2032 owing to extreme weather events.

Transitioning to a low-carbon economy entails significant upfront costs and policy challenges. Mitigation measures (such as investment in renewable energy infrastructure, energy efficiency improvements and other emission reduction strategies) require substantial financial resources and long-term planning. Green investment, both public and private, will be essential in order to facilitate the transition to a sustainable economy.[19] Carbon-pricing mechanisms such as carbon taxes offer a potential source of revenue that could offset some of the fiscal costs of climate policies.[20] Recent IMF estimates based on a New Keynesian dynamic general equilibrium model suggest that primary deficits in advanced economies could increase by around 0.4 percentage points of GDP over the next few decades as a result of a policy package designed to achieve net-zero emissions in 2050.[21] However, this assumes that a large share of public spending on green investment and subsidies is financed through carbon tax revenues.

The macroeconomic and financial consequences of climate change and related policies can also have an indirect impact on public finances. The economic consequences of climate change (which include productivity losses, disruptions to supply chains and declines in agricultural output) can dampen GDP growth. The resulting contraction in economic activity can, in turn, erode government revenues and result in higher debt servicing costs. Model simulations conducted by the Network of Central Banks and Supervisors for Greening the Financial System (NGFS) suggest that some euro area countries could experience significant real output losses. When conducting such analysis, the cost of different transition policies[22] needs to be set against the reduction in physical risks from climate-related events. For instance, in the “net-zero by 2050” scenario, which limits global warming to 1.5°C through stringent climate policies and innovation, real output losses are fairly limited (Chart 4, panel a); however, the costly transition policies lead to spikes in inflation and relatively persistent increases in interest rates (which rise by 1 percentage point on average; Chart 4, panel b). Increases in interest rates tend to reflect the inflationary pressure created by carbon prices, as well as increased demand for investment.[23] The higher interest rates in the NGFS’s “net‑zero by 2050” scenario are the single most important driver of the long-term interest-growth differential. For instance, for a country with debt totalling 60% of GDP, a 1 percentage point increase in the interest-growth differential would, over time, result in the annual debt service burden rising by 0.6 percentage points of GDP. Naturally, these simulations are based on strong assumptions and contain a large degree of model uncertainty.[24] Several aspects – including the drivers of rising long-term interest rates and the role of monetary policy – need to be investigated further, and the ECB is actively contributing to those research efforts.

Under EU rules, at least 37% of all RRF funds disbursed must be spent on the green transition. While Member States often choose to spend significantly higher shares (ranging from 37.4% in Lithuania to 68.8% in Luxembourg and Malta), RRF funds can only cover a limited proportion of a country’s climate expenditure needs.

Chart 4

Simulating the impact of climate change under different transition scenarios

a) Impact on real GDP growth rates

(percentage point changes; averages for the period 2024-50)

b) Impact on long-term interest rates

(percentage point changes; averages for the period 2024-50)

Sources: NGFS long-term scenarios (Phase IV) and ECB calculations.
Notes: See footnote 22 for a description of NGFS scenarios. Countries are ordered on the basis of the average cross-scenario impact. Data refer to geometric means over the period 2024‑50 and are not available for Croatia, Cyprus, Luxembourg or Malta. NGFS simulations employ three different models (GCAM, MESSAGEix-GLOBIOM and REMIND-MAgPIE), and the results presented here are averages of the findings for those three models.

6 Cumulative impact

This section provides a rough and purely indicative estimate of the possible fiscal burden arising from the developments described in the previous sections. A single indicator aggregates the various components (Chart 5 and Box 1), estimating the fiscal adjustment that each euro area country would need to implement as of 2024 and maintain throughout the simulation horizon.[25] The shared long-term target is a government debt-to-GDP ratio of 60% (as referred to in the Treaty) by 2070.[26] This fiscal gap measure is indicative and requires further analysis and interpretation to reach normative conclusions. Countries will need to ascertain and execute their respective adjustment paths. Moreover, the implementation of more ambitious structural reforms – notably those that support long-term growth – would help to reduce the fiscal burden, which is computed here on the basis of currently projected long-term growth rates. This is also the reason why the issue of digitalisation is not included in this exercise, as the benefits of digitalisation could potentially compensate for some of the fiscal costs incurred.

Chart 5

Overview of fiscal efforts required in response to specific challenges

(percentages of GDP)

Sources: 2024 Ageing Report, European Commission’s Debt Sustainability Monitor 2023, NGFS Phase IV simulations, IMF’s October 2023 Fiscal Monitor, NATO, Eurostat and ECB calculations.
Notes: The chart depicts the required immediate and permanent one-off improvement in the ratio of structural primary balance to GDP to bring the debt ratio to 60% of GDP by 2070, incorporating financing for any additional expenditure until 2070 arising from an ageing population, defence and climate. See Box 1 for a description of the methodology.

Achieving a government debt-to-GDP ratio of 60% by 2070 from today’s debt levels would require euro area governments to immediately and permanently increase their primary balances by 2% of GDP on average (dark blue and yellow bars in Chart 5). 16 euro area countries would require fiscal adjustments just to maintain their current debt levels, with necessary average savings of 1.4% of GDP (blue bars). Going further and reducing debt to 60% of GDP would, on average, require additional savings totalling 0.6% of GDP in the euro area, with high-debt countries having the largest adjustment needs (yellow bars).

The additional challenges discussed above, excluding digitalisation, could widen the euro area’s average fiscal deficit by approximately a further 3% of GDP.[27] Of those challenges, demographic ageing is expected to result in the largest fiscal burden over the next five decades, potentially necessitating additional spending of up to 4% of GDP for some countries, and 1.2% for the euro area on average. As regards the NATO target for defence expenditure, four of the NATO members in the euro area are already spending the targeted amount of 2% of GDP, while the other 12 face additional burdens of up to 1% of GDP, resulting in an average burden of 0.5% of GDP at euro area level. For the four non-NATO countries – Ireland, Cyprus, Malta and Austria – there is no formal requirement to spend a specific amount on defence. However, Chart 5 plots the gap vis-à-vis 2% of GDP in the light of the changing geopolitical environment.[28] For climate change, assuming a “net-zero by 2050” scenario which limits global warming to 1.5°C, we estimate an average cost increase totalling 1.1% of GDP at the level of the euro area as a whole. This is driven by the 0.4 percentage point increase in the primary deficit-to-GDP ratio that was calculated by the IMF and the additional interest burden on debt stocks that was projected by the NGFS.[29]

The necessary fiscal adjustment is large by historical standards, but not without precedent. At the same time, for all of the challenges discussed above, there is considerable cross-country heterogeneity in the required fiscal efforts, with estimates of gaps ranging from 0.5% to almost 10% of GDP. In the past, large fiscal adjustments were mainly observed in response to major fiscal crises and in the presence of sizeable debt overhangs. Belgium, Ireland and Finland maintained cyclically adjusted primary surpluses of over 5% of GDP on average for more than a decade in the 1990s and early 2000s.[30] In some countries, the fiscal pressures discussed may not strengthen in the short term; however, there is no room for complacency, as the longer the adjustment is postponed, the larger the eventual adjustment cost will be.

Moreover, additional fiscal burdens may well emerge in the medium term. For instance, the model-based simulations used in this article exclude the digitalisation gap, the long-term implications of which are still hard to grasp. Furthermore, one does not need to go back very far in time to find a large fiscal shock appearing out of the blue: the euro area’s government debt-to-GDP ratio increased by a total of 13 percentage points in 2020 in response to the COVID-19 pandemic. At the same time, the simulation of climate change is based on simplified assumptions and on the unlikely premise that limiting global warming to 1.5°C is still feasible. It also does not capture the impact of societal repercussions (such as conflict), tipping points or macroeconomic effects (such as changes to prices and productivity). This suggests that there could be substantial additional fiscal costs associated with climate change.[31] On the upside, however, the simulation may understate the potential positive economic side effects of increased public spending, such as spending on digitalisation. While the demographic ageing and climate change scenarios are built on a set of internally consistent assumptions, which also capture macroeconomic effects, the modelling of defence spending does not take account of the possible macroeconomic impact (e.g. the potential for the benefits of technological progress to spill over from the defence sector to the wider economy).

Box 1
Methodology of the fiscal gap indicator

In order to make the diverse fiscal long-term pressures comparable in a single indicator per country, we compute the immediate and permanent improvement in the structural primary balance required to bring the debt ratio to 60% of GDP by 2070. In addition to accounting for the adjustment need to stabilise and then reduce the initial debt level to the target level, the indicator incorporates financing for any additional expenditure arising from an ageing population, defence needs and climate change.

Deriving the fiscal gap and its components

Government debt in euro at the end of any given year is the sum of four components: (i) the debt at the end of the previous year, (ii) the interest accrued on that debt, (iii) the negative primary balance, and (iv) any debt-deficit-adjustment (DDA). Expressed in terms of GDP, in an economy with a balanced budget and zero DDA, debt-to-GDP grows every year proportional to the interest-growth differential (IGD). The IGD is the ratio between (i) one plus the average nominal interest rate and (ii) one plus the nominal GDP growth rate. However, the development of government debt is also determined by future primary balances and any DDA. From the above accounting identity we can apply the net present value (NPV) approach, discounting future flows by the annual IGDs and thus making them comparable across different time horizons. For instance, for reducing the current debt ratio by a given percentage, a government could apply a certain amount of savings in the current year or the same savings discounted by IGD in the following year. More generally, the difference between (i) the NPV of government debt as a percentage of GDP at a future date, and (ii) current government debt equals the NPV of the (negative) primary balances plus any DDA flows between today and the future date.

We define as our fiscal gap indicator the necessary permanent improvement in the ratio of the structural primary balance to GDP as of 2024 to reach a government debt of 60% of GDP by 2070. To determine the NPV of the fiscal flows needed to meet the target, we take (i) the 2023 government debt as a percentage of GDP, (ii) subtract the NPV of 60% of GDP debt discounted from 2070 to 2023, and (iii) add the NPV of negative primary balances plus DDA flows from 2024 to 2070. This NPV is then converted into a steady flow of primary balances that guarantee the attainment of the final target.

This approach can also be used to provide a breakdown of the fiscal gap into the different drivers. Looking at the equation below, we split the effort to reach the 60% debt ratio by 2070 into five components. These are the adjustments needed to (i) achieve the 2023 debt ratio (d0) by 2070 taking into account the starting primary balance and any DDA, (ii) reduce the 2070 debt ratio to 60% of GDP, (iii) cover ageing-related costs, (iv) cover additional defence expenditure needs, and (v) cover climate change-related costs.

gap=1at-1d0-d0aT-pbBaset-ddatat+d0-60%aT+agetat+deftat+climatetat

In this equation, at and aT are the NPV discount factors at period t and in 2070 respectively, and Σ refers to the sum of flows from 2024 to 2070.

Assumptions for fiscal pressures and future interest-growth differentials

Our approach is similar to the S1 indicator presented in the European Commission’s Debt Sustainability Monitor (DSM) 2023, also with regard to the assumptions for primary balances, the interest-growth differential and ageing costs.[32] There are, however, three notable differences in the approach used here. First, the one-off fiscal adjustment is assumed to happen in 2024, compared with a two-year delay in the DSM. Second, we assume a constant structural primary fiscal balance over the projection horizon in order to avoid double-counting of legislated climate and defence measures. Third, we include these two additional components, which do not feature in the Commission’s indicator.

7 Conclusions

Issues such as demographic ageing, increased defence expenditure, digitalisation and climate change will result in significant fiscal burdens in the decades ahead. These developments will be challenging enough in isolation, and countries will face all of them simultaneously. Consequently, action needs to be taken today – especially in high-debt countries facing elevated interest rates and the associated risks.[33] Economic policies should seek to gradually reduce high levels of public debt and prepare for the future, which will also help to ensure a sound environment for the conduct of the euro area’s single monetary policy.

  1. This figure peaked at 20.2 years in 2019 (i.e. pre-pandemic).

  2. See European Commission, “2024 Ageing Report: Economic & Budgetary Projections for the EU Member States (2022-2070)”, European Economy – Institutional Papers, No 279, April 2024.

  3. See the article entitled “Social spending, a euro area cross-country comparison”, Economic Bulletin, Issue 5, ECB, 2019.

  4. Only three of the 32 current NATO members achieved that target in 2014. By 2023, however, the number had risen to 11, and it is expected to reach 18 by the end of 2024. See “Pre-ministerial press conference by NATO Secretary General Jens Stoltenberg”, 14 February 2024.

  5. See also Freier, M., Ioannou, D. and Vergara Caffarelli, F., “EU public goods and military spending”, Box 16 in “The EU’s Open Strategic Autonomy from a central banking perspective – Challenges to the monetary policy landscape from a changing geopolitical environment”, Occasional Paper Series, No 311, ECB, March 2023.

  6. See the Commission’s website for more details.

  7. See Kiel Institute for the World Economy, “Ukraine Support Tracker” database.

  8. See World Bank, “Ukraine – Third Rapid Damage and Needs Assessment (RDNA3): February 2022 – December 2023”, February 2024.

  9. See the article entitled “Fiscal policy and high inflation”, Economic Bulletin, Issue 2, ECB, 2023, and the box entitled “Update on euro area fiscal policy responses to the energy crisis and high inflation” in the same issue.

  10. See Di Sano, M., Gunnella, V. and Lebastard, L., “Deglobalisation: risk or reality?”, The ECB Blog, 12 July 2023.

  11. Restructuring production chains in order to prioritise geographical proximity over efficiency could result in increased production costs, a fall in employment and disruption to supply chains. This would ultimately have an impact on government revenues from corporate taxation, personal income tax, sales taxes and international trade. Additionally, it could also discourage investment in innovation, further hampering long-term economic growth and tax revenues.

  12. See European Commission, “Identifying Europe’s recovery needs” (SWD/2020/98 final), 27 May 2020.

  13. See “Delivering the Digital Decade with EU investments”, Chapter 5 of European Commission, “Implementation of the Digital Decade objectives and the Digital Rights and Principles” (SWD/2023/570 final), 27 September 2023.

  14. See Olczyk, M. and Kuc-Czarnecka, M., “Digital transformation and economic growth – DESI improvement and implementation”, Technological and Economic Development of Economy, Vol. 28, No 3, 2022, pp. 775-803.

  15. The global economic losses are estimated to total $4.3 trillion. See World Meteorological Organization, “Atlas of Mortality and Economic Losses from Weather, Climate and Water-Related Hazards (1970-2021)”, 22 May 2023.

  16. See Feyen, L., Ciscar, J.C., Gosling, S., Ibarreta, D. and Soria, A. (eds.), “Climate change impacts and adaptation in Europe”, JRC PESETA IV final report, 2020.

  17. See ECB and EIOPA, “Policy options to reduce the climate insurance protection gap”, Discussion Paper, April 2023.

  18. See Gagliardi, N., Arévalo, P. and Pamies, S., “The Fiscal Impact of Extreme Weather and Climate Events: Evidence for EU Countries”, European Economy Discussion Papers, No 168, European Commission, July 2022.

  19. In Europe, for instance, an estimated €275 billion of Next Generation EU and REPowerEU funds will be used to support investment in clean technology, while €118 billion has been set aside to help fund the transition to clean energy between now and 2027 under the Cohesion Policy.

  20. See the article entitled “Fiscal policies to mitigate climate change in the euro area”, Economic Bulletin, Issue 6, ECB, 2022.

  21. See Chapter 1 of the IMF’s October 2023 Fiscal Monitor.

  22. NGFS Phase IV simulates the impact in terms of physical and transition risks of five transition scenarios relative to a hypothetical baseline scenario with no physical or transition risk. “Net-zero by 2050” is an ambitious scenario that limits global warming to 1.5°C through stringent climate policies and innovation, reaching net-zero CO₂ emissions around 2050. “Delayed transition” assumes that annual global emissions do not start to decline until 2030, with strong policies then being needed to keep global warming below 2°C. “Below 2°C” is a scenario where the stringency of climate policies is gradually increased, giving a 67% chance of keeping global warming below 2°C. “NDCs” (nationally determined contributions) is a scenario where all current NDCs are implemented (including NDCs that have been pledged but not yet implemented). The “fragmented world” scenario assumes delayed and divergent climate policy ambition globally, leading to elevated transition risks in some countries and high physical risks everywhere owing to the overall ineffectiveness of the transition.

  23. For these macroeconomic scenarios, the NGFS applies the NiGEM model, under which central banks follow the Taylor rule and long-term fiscal solvency is ensured. Furthermore, there is an assumption that 50% of the carbon price will be passed straight on to consumer prices. In the NiGEM model, the high levels of investment can result in persistently higher real interest rates owing to several interrelated factors. First, heightened demand for investment can lead to a crowding-out effect, whereby increased competition for available funds in capital markets drives borrowing costs up. And second, inflation expectations can, if influenced by increased investment activity, prompt lenders to demand higher nominal interest rates, driving up real interest rates. At the same time, the concrete formulation of central bank behaviour has major implications for the interest rate path in the model simulations.

  24. See, for example, the article entitled “The macroeconomic implications of the transition to a low-carbon economy”, Economic Bulletin, Issue 5, ECB, 2023 and the box entitled “Assessing the macroeconomic effects of climate change transition policies”, Economic Bulletin, Issue 1, ECB, 2024.

  25. See also the section entitled “Fiscal Policy Sustainability and Structural Spending Pressures” in Chapter 1 of the IMF’s April 2024 Fiscal Monitor, which presents details of a comparable exercise and reaches similar conclusions. The IMF shows that advanced economies are facing additional public spending pressures equivalent to 7.4% of GDP by 2030. This comprises increases of 1 percentage point for interest payments, 2 percentage points for climate spending (under the “net‑zero by 2050” scenario), 2.9 percentage points for demographic ageing, 0.6 percentage points for defence spending, and 1 percentage point for industrial policy and the UN’s Sustainable Development Goals.

  26. The government debt-to-GDP ratio of 60% is referred to in Article 126(2) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union and specified in Protocol No 12 annexed to the Treaty.

  27. The exclusion of digitalisation stems mainly from the limited number of reliable forecasts and the lack of clarity regarding interaction with other key macroeconomic and financial variables.

  28. See also European Commission, “Defence Investment Gaps Analysis and Way Forward”, Joint communication to the European Parliament, the European Council, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions, 18 May 2022. For Luxembourg, a target of 1.7% of GDP is assumed, given its commitment to spending 2% of gross national income.

  29. Climate shock scenario data, which are only available until 2050 in the source material, are constant-extrapolated. The Greek NGFS climate shock is adjusted to reflect the fact that debt with fixed rates and long maturities accounts for a significant share of total debt.

  30. See the box entitled “Past experience of EU countries with sustaining large primary budget surpluses”, Monthly Bulletin, ECB, June 2011.

  31. The recently published UN Emissions Gap Report found that even in the most optimistic scenario, the chance of limiting global warming to 1.5°C is only 14%, leaving open a large possibility that global warming will exceed 2°C or even 3°C. See United Nations Environment Programme, “Emissions Gap Report 2023: Broken Record – Temperatures hit new highs, yet world fails to cut emissions (again)”, November 2023; and Elderson, F., ““Know thyself” – avoiding policy mistakes in light of the prevailing climate science”, keynote speech at the Delphi Economic Forum IX, 12 April 2024.

  32. See European Commission, “Debt Sustainability Monitor 2023”, Institutional Papers, No 271, 22 March 2024.

  33. See Adrian, T., Gaspar, V. and Gourinchas, P.-O., “The Fiscal and Financial Risks of a High-Debt, Slow-Growth World”, IMF Blog, 28 March 2024.